SHORT essays on CITIES
The City: Brief Essays Martin Krieger 6/1/17 6:56 PM
These
brief essays were written either for a podcast or as epitomes of lectures in my
courses on cities. There is repetition and changes of emphasis, but I have not
tried to edit much. And the first and second pieces were deliberately written
as previews of what is to come. I have posted some of this before, but I thought to put it all out again.
MK
What
we know about cities
When we talk about urban life, there are some scholarly findings—many
obvious—that suggest how policies and plans actually work. It’s remarkable how
often these facts are ignored.
Cities take up space, and one’s location in a city
(often with respect to a central or other significant district) determines
house prices and rents and commutes, as well as job opportunities and safety
and schools. Within that space, there are public spaces and parks and
cemeteries, private spaces such as homes and businesses, and shopping,
commercial and industrial activities, and services and bureaucracies.
(E-commerce does not replace those actual spaces, it would seem.) All cities
are built by government and by private developers, the latter under the purview
of government, and in general density is necessary if these endeavors are to be
financially viable and socially interesting. Developers and owners need to be assured
that their title and property rights are firm if they are to invest and build
and buy for the long term. Moreover, government and utility companies must
provide the infrastructure of roads and power and water and refuse removal, if
a location is to be viable at all. And much of the stuff needed to live and
build comes from elsewhere, other cities and the hinterlands.
There needs to be a way of gathering money into
bundles, through taxes and banking, so that government budgets and private
loans are available for construction and improvements. Zoning, informal or
legal, makes sure that residents and nuisances (say, a garbage dump) are not
too adjacent, and they encourage the advantages or like activities or
businesses being close to each other.
Cities are attractive for migrants from the
countryside and perhaps from other cities. There are as well inflows of
finance, power, and goods and foodstuffs, and outflows of other goods and
pollutants. Moreover, there are internal flows of people, goods, and intermediate
products. The effect of these concentrations is likely to lead to much greater
numbers of interactions and outputs than might be anticipated by counting
population or wealth.
Cities almost always emphasize the differences among
people, in their talents, their backgrounds, and their races, just because
people are right next to each other and encounter each other in commerce and
social life, and because in such an economy the division of labor and
specialization are great advantages. Usually, those differences lead to
hierarchies, where some people and institutions are considered better than
others, and the spatial isolation of the various levels in the hierarchy—albeit
they breathe the same air and often must interact intimately. That makes it
harder for those at the tops of hierarchies to ignore those toward the
bottom—for the tops’ security and their well-being depends on a stable society,
one that will be threatened by these hierarchies. Societal safety nets serve
the interests of those at the top by securing and legitimating their status. At
the same time, cities are places where people lose their original
identities—from their neighborhoods, from the countryside--developing more
homogeneous ones and then new distinctive identities.
Of course, people are born, grow, go to school, form
families and new households, find work, and eventually die. This life cycle
sets demands on what cities must provide, hospitals and cemeteries for example.
The other major influences on city life are those of politics and regulation
and the sacred. There is government, and its powers are substantial and often
it regulates life. Moreover, the economy and social relations set up other
regulations. And usually, there are sacred commitments—religion, school, sports
teams—that provide cultural regulation.
To attend to
these features of cities—location, infrastructure, finance, flows of people and
goods, differentiation and hierarchy, and the life cycle and its regulation—is
to be able to figure out how to make our lives better.
The Urban Context means: density, diversity, dispersion and
concentration, the need for explicit spaces to carry on life and work, a
complex market for buying and selling and so the divisions of labor and
production, with a wide variety of consumption. There are public spaces. People
actually encounter each other in public, and people are seen by strangers.
There is as well groupings, as in neighborhoods, ethnicities, classes, and
races, that lead to spatial agglomerations. Those who do not do well are likely
to be encountered by all.
Cities are highly differentiated in space, activity,
people… That differentiation is often
expressed in heterogeneity, that is parts that do not mix well (what is
sometimes called ??? about difference} it also about hierarchy. And given the
variety of people and activities, such hierarchy may have pervasive effects.
What we call jobs and professions become more varied,
and they exist at all because the demand for work that must be done is likely
to be highly differentiated, and so there is in effect a market for labor.
Factories surely need workers, but there need to be customers for their
products, and if there is diversity and density, there is likely room for a
large number of producers of differentiated products.
Cities, as they grow and differentiate, and as they
have an influx of people from elsewhere, become rather less intimate. People
come to cities because for them alienation from an intimate community may well
be very uncomfortable, and they accept the consequences of such alienation as
the cost of freedom. Moreover, they may find intimate friends who are not so
nearby to them but are within the city—since with more people there is greater
likelihood of matching.
Cities grow by natural increase, by in-migration, by
economic developments and by particular advantages that become apparent when
they contribute to the economy. Cities are networked with other cities and with
the hinterlands, for goods and food, for services, for intermediate products.
Modes of transportation, if they are inexpensive and reliable, encourage those
networks, and within cities they allow for a dispersion of work, commerce,
play, residence. Communications, whether by post, telephone, or various
electronic means, allow for the management of widespread enterprises (rail and
the telegraph), for maintaining relationships that are commercial or personal,
and for making connections among otherwise distant entities. Cities tend to
become more dense with transactions and interactions, at least until congestion
becomes too much. Infill is common, since there would always seem to be
mismatched spaces and activities, and insofar as you can figure out how to take
advantage of such mismatches, you are likely to thrive.
Cities decline, sometimes due to invasion or disease,
sometimes because other cities take over some of their advantages.
Flows of material, capital, energy are intense, with
major flow-ways among cities and within a hierarchy of cities.
Someones have to build the city, perhaps government,
more likely entrepreneurs and individuals. Entrepreneurs want some assurance
that property will not be taken away from them, by brigands or by government.
Real property is always in tension with movable property (finance and money),
and insofar as money is available for investment and building, real property
will be developed. Whether there by hot-bedding, garage housing, pop-ups, …
there is likely to be impromptu use of space, often not legal.
It matters where you are located. Usually it is more
expensive closer to the center, or one of the centers, but in compensation
transport times are shorter and transport is less expensive. Insofar as you
need to interact face-to-face, you want to be located near as many of your
intimates as possible. In general it is
hard to be self-sufficient in a city, largely because land needed for animals
and agriculture is not readily available.
The public policy and city planning issues include:
providing streets and roadways, sewerage, water and utilities, safety and
security (crime is more likely and possible if the population density is high),
fire protection. Schooling is almost always locally provided (in the US), and
the same for health facilities. Public health is a genuine problem since
density means that disease can spread readily. Freight and food-distribution
must be allowed, and there must be sufficient shelter provided either publicly
or privately. Religious institutions, with many sects and religions, take up
space. Government figures out how to divide space so that less-compatible uses
are better separated yet allows for flexibility. Cities consume resources, many of which are
located at a distance, and they convert resources into goods that others want.
They also concentrate resources associated with human capital. And disaster is
not uncommon, whether fire or flood, disease, or invasion. How do you make for
protection and recovery?
Politically, cities allow for more intimate
governance, but also for more corruption it would seem. But cities usually are
under the purview of counties, special districts, states and federal
governments. Revenue is raised from taxes and fees, and there are substantial
exchanges with counties, districts, and other governments. Cities are not at
all autonomous, for they have to accord with larger regional or national
imperatives.
There is a deep connection between what people do,
their actions, in toto, and the built environment, and we might study just one
and infer something about the other. There is another connection between the
structure of the city and its history (built environment structure, people
structure). What we see now is an accumulation of past actions and buildings,
as well as destruction and rebuilding.
Hence, these connections must be informed by history, and in no sense
are we in a long-term equilibrium.
Space and Place in Cities
Cities are places and they take up space. Their spaces may grow by
development and annexation so that two cities grow into each other.
Cities are dense,
articulated and particularized, excluding and including, outspreading and
infilling places, with flows of people and goods within the city, and without
to other cities in the nation and internationally.
Cities are regulated
by their economies, laws, their local geographies (eg. a river). Neighborhoods
are relatively homogeneous and self-identified places, usually commercial,
residential, and industrial uses are present--but sometimes only one or two.
Cities grow by in-migration, often of diverse peoples, who may then be pushed
into or choose to live close to each other (but not their children and
grand-children).
Cities provide jobs and workers, religious places,
educational institutions (less usually rather than more universal, until
recently). They are almost always governed locally, although the nation or
other nations may well control that.
Cities are usually
built by developers, who have access to capital and power--developers might
well be the state or preferred agents. They are rebuilt after devastation,
after decline, with robust economies helping. In very robust economies they are
overbuilt, and that overhang takes a while to be worked out.
Geography matters:
rivers, hills, local resources. But so does the interests of the state or of
entrepreneurs.
Cities have some sort
of public streets, perhaps in a grid, perhaps with multiple colliding grids,
perhaps with neighborhoods with complex streetways. Those arrangements are
sometimes rebuilt, with enormous disruption (Paris).
Spaces are usually
private, but there are public spaces as in parks and streets and public
facilities. The private provision of public space is common, although such
public spaces are still under private control. This has consequences for
political demonstrations, photographing, etc.
Spaces are marked by
aural ambience (quiet, street noise, factory noise, hawkers) and by other
sensory qualities (visual complexity, smells and fragrances, and sometimes even
feel). The urban sensorium is always experienced, but often not even noted as
we go about our activities. Stopping to smell the roses is occasioned by
something stopping us in our tracks.
Aerial and birds-eye
views, historically from the tops of hills and or imagined as such, are vital
for getting an overall sense. But walking will reveal details and
flavors.
Cities are not ideas,
they are actual places with social and economic factors that are found in part
by looking and in part by deep investigation. Cities are always planned, by the
state, by developers, by political actors. What might look like a jumble has a
history that makes sense. Favellas, the hillside communities in Rio de Janeiro,
may look like a jumble, but the residents have discerned a plan among the
complexity, in part by informal regulation. Cities are always replanned and redesigned,
usually in part and pieces, almost never wholesale.
Cities must have
provision for water, waste, accessibility (roads,...), safety and security, and
power. Even charming seemingly unplanned cities, those wonderful hillside
cities (as in The American) must be ordered, often by the
topography and by what others have done. But cities are also quite efficient,
in providing for what people need.
People who live
outside of cities, almost always use the services provided by the city. Yet the
city needs the produce of the hinterland, for food, for construction materials,
for waste disposal. Cities always pollute, but at least pollution may be sent
elsewhere or isolated.
The Structure and Dynamics of
Cities
Cities develop in space and over time, and places are known as aging or
renewing or perhaps stable neighborhoods of a particular era. We might
understand urban flows and structure in terms of the movements of people or in terms of the built and social
environment: People interact with each other through the exchange of goods,
money, information, just what defines institutions and neighborhoods… and they
are most likely to interact with neighbors, close-by in space, or status, or
role. [Not all interactions are fair or legal, and those that are not are
likely to be occasions for extracting a premium.]
Moreover, cities are heterogeneous and hierarchical.
Stocks and flows of people and goods and property are intimately related, in
space and in time. Disruption, invention and import, decay and export, account
for imbalances. There is lots of fluctuation and change that appears to be
unavoidable.
When we talk about cities, we often treat persons as
simplified or abstract individuals--each with a small number of properties,
such as age, income, race, gender.
Collectively, as flows and stocks, they then exhibit orderliness or
symmetries (spatial, wealth, status) at various scales. These cultural
categories then give meaning to what people do.
We might learn about urban life by inserting something
out of place or alien to the culture, a “foreign” object, and finding out that
we are in trouble. Usually, these inconveniences are minor, and they do not
have lasting effects. But, during extraordinary times, such as economic
downturns, flood, or invasion, we are able to see more of what is ordinarily
hidden.
‘
Clustering in Cities and in Matter
Cities show spatial clustering of people and enterprise, by class, by
race, by kind of industry. Sometimes that clustering is deliberate, sometimes
it is by chance, or market mechanisms, or the unplanned effect of regulations.
Physical scientists understand clustering and
orderliness when they think of the forces between molecules or particles. A
liquid might freeze—its molecules clustering in an orderly fashion--so we have
ice. Matter is modeled as a 3-d grid on which actual molecules are attached to
the vertices; and, perhaps, something like electric fields may be attached to
the links between vertices.
If the molecules interact with their nearest neighbors, the lattice or grid may develop
clusters of like particles, in seas of unlike particles, in seas of like
particles… If the temperature is low
enough, the particles form a sea of like particles, and they are said to be aligned--in
effect, there is freezing. If the temperature is high enough, there is very
little clustering at all. There is randomness and heterogeneity.
Those electric fields allow for new phenomena. Namely,
particles become entangled with each other through those links and it becomes
impossible to separate them from each other. Individuals are “confined,” so to
speak, never to be on their own.
In actual cities we see orderliness, heterogeneity,
and confinement—depending on social and economic conditions.
It’s not as if people behave like molecules. Rather,
there are common sources for the behavior of individuals in crowds.
Flows and Finance
Given an Economy and Space, both highly differentiated, there are
substantial flows within and among cities. Transactions usually take place when
we are in the same space (sometimes cyber, sometimes mail, sometimes exchanges
as for stocks or grains), and so movement is almost always necessary.
Migration from the countryside, from other regions,
and from other countries populate (or depopulate) a city. Cities offer freedom
from rural and agricultural work, and job growth is usually urban (but see
mining, for example). Moreover, within a city there is migration among
neighborhoods, people moving up, down, sideways. Places and areas become
differentiated by wealth, ethnicity, race, political attitude—people moving to
find a good fit between themselves and their neighbors, although for many there
are blatant restrictions to their movement.
Cities also extend themselves, often into agricultural
land, and grow spatially (in part, by annexation) so that they bump into
neighboring cities and topographic features. People like city amenities: water,
power, police, schools,… Moreover, goods have to move between places because
where they are produced and where consumed are often far from each other. Such freight is quite demanding of space,
from roadways, rail, warehouses, and ports. Moreover, services are often
centralized, as in a hospital, and people need to travel to get those
services. “Sprawl” is a term used to
describe urban extension before there is densification in that area.
Utilities, what we expect to be Flows available
whenever we need them: electricity, natural gas, clean water, sewerage, storm
sewers, communications by means of cables and microwave,… must go along with
populations and spatial extents, and they form networks and systems that have
to be coordinated. Roadways and rail lines are part of this utility system.
Communications may affect material flows, encouraging business, visiting, and
extended families. And people have to live someplace, work someplace, and get
to work, go home, shop--so there is such a traffic flow. In these systems there
is sometimes overload and congestion, since peak demand is much larger than
average demand. Regulation, pricing, and overbuilding may deal with such
overload; often the main cost is delays and lost time. Coordination is needed
among the spaces, the users, the flows, and the productions. People constantly
scheme and game the system to find ways of dealing with congestion, or to
create scarcity and so be able to charge more.
Flows are provided for publicly, by private
enterprises, and by enterprises given rights by public entities. Taxes, bonded
indebtedness, and private capital pay for the production of these flow-ways,
and users are charged fees for their consumption of flows. Often the capital
cost of production is very great, and so the indebtedness is paid for by future
users, rather than savings made before the facilities are constructed. It is
always an economic and a political decision to build a flow-way, for we may
deem some ways to be so crucial that they do not have to pay their way. In the
US, freedom to flow and move is taken as a given, and that you are not at the
center does not mean that you don’t get flows out to where you are.
Accessibility matters politically and legally. Yet, those who have more get
much more, those poor, much less.
Cities are mostly built by private enterprise, with
systematic help from the public sector. Zoning assures builders that
conflicting uses are unlikely to be nearby, governments provide home loans and
or, more likely, guarantees to banks so that the loans are less risky, and
government may well subsidize private projects or industries to encourage job
growth and tax increments. Bankruptcy law means that those who take risks do
not end up in jail, although they may lose their assets.
Property may well be owned or under governmental
control, and some is sold off or given to private individuals. To get people to
build, they need to be assured that their property will not be arbitrarily
taken from them, for buildings, and other such, have long useful lifetimes. You
cannot get their total benefits immediately. As importantly, capital is needed
to construct the built environment, and few have that capital in their back
pockets. Squatters and homesteaders and renters acquire their property (it may
not be ownership and be tenure), whatever its security, through legislation and
political action.
The finance system
(banks, various private funds) gathers the savings of individuals, of other
funds (pensions, investment vehicles), so that the large capital demands of
builders might be available. In the US, the federal government has been in the
business of encouraging home ownership (and so home-building), by means of
guaranteeing those loans and otherwise making capital available. Various
schemes have developed to encourage the flow of private funds into real
restate: real estate investment trusts (REIT), mortgage backed securities and
variations thereon. Since, in general risk being higher demands greater reward
(interest rate, say), these schemes try to modulate risk while offering bigger
rewards than usual. (Future economic growth may make current bonds and loans
much easier to pay off, and inflation does its work as well, but those who buy
such bonds demand some premium for these risks.) One needs good measures of
that risk, and rating agencies have proved unable to be honest brokers, and
sellers have proved to be unreliable. Moreover, systematic risk, when there is
strong correlation of risks, means that residual risk can be substantial and
catastrophic. For sellers, transaction fees have come dominate the steady
stream of income from loans, so there is little incentive to be reliable (they
have no skin in the game once they sell a loan).
On the other hand,
local governments use taxes (property, sales) and bonded indebtedness for the
parts of the city built by public entities, such as roads, or electrical
systems, or schools, or… Again, future
users pay for the provision of flow-ways. There may be tax breaks for income
from municipal bonds, so making it less expensive for a city to issue them.
Although there are periods of growth in the actual
value of real estate, the costs of maintenance, taxes, and the changing market
make that less sure than is commonly believed. If you have large influxes of
people and industry into an area, it is likely that real estate prices will
rise. Real estate markets will fall if
there is a lack of liquidity (loans), neighborhoods and places decay, and
bubbles burst. On the other hand real estate and buildings last a long time,
much longer than planned, and population growth is common (but declines happen
as well). People do make money in real estate, from their homes and their
entrepreneurial ventures, and their investments, but this is a volatile asset
and the chances for losing money and bankruptcy are not uncommon
Heterogeneity and Hierarchy in the City
We have talked about Space, Economy,
Building, and Finance—and in what sense these are urban topics. Now I want to
focus on people. Characteristic of cities is the larger number of people
close-by each other, and that as a whole they are quite varied in race, class,
wealth, health, … The reason for this is that unless migration and jobs and
procreation are regulated, there will be a variety of people who end up in a
city, at least for a while. Migrations, which often are group migrations, means
that there can be very different and new groups in a city. In the process of
social and economic interaction, some people become better off, some become
worse off. It’s easy to see what your neighbors are like, and because of the
flows of people, you have a sense, at least, of your not-so-neighbors. Since it
is virtually impossible to grow your own food or put up your own shelter, in
most cities, being poor may well make it impossible for you to thrive. At the
same time, if your life depends on having a job or doing transactions with
others, the variety of people and industries in most cities means that you are
likely to be better off than if you lived in a more isolated area.
If there is heterogeneity, there is also hierarchy. We somehow convince
ourselves that skin color, nationality, ethnic group, wealth, personal
attractiveness, etc. comes not in a variety but in a hierarchy, where some ways
are better than others. Poverty among mendicant monks is not the way most
people view the poor in their city. It usually is a plus to be whiter, taller,
richer; and then certain particular characteristics (ethnicity) may put you in
a particular hierarchy (better Armenian than Azeri?).
Why is there poverty in a rich and vibrant city, we might ask? Why are biases
hierarchized? Why is there not only an economy, but also an informal economy,
and an underground economy? Why do some people participate in criminality? Why
are some people comparatively healthy, other subject to chronic disease? Why
are people separated in somewhat more homogeneous neighborhoods, and what does
this have to do with zoning and discrimination? What are the consequences of
massive migrations or the US’s legacy of slavery? Why do some people choose to
live in a place with little amenity, while for others amenity motivates them.
And can people make such choices?
Whatever the answers, the crucial point is that cities make heterogeneity
inevitable, and people make hierarchy almost inevitable. Moreover, it helps to
start out with advantages (wealth, education, …), but people sometimes squander
those advantages. And substantial changes in the society, such as the decline
of industrial jobs in a city, can have profound consequences for those who are
most vulnerable. That unions are much less influential than they were
40-50 years ago influences what part of the economic pie goes to those who work
for others, and that too creates vast differences.
What
does all of this, the last two paragraphs, have to do with cities? One might
well have all these phenomena in rural and agricultural areas. But cities make
the differences and hierarchies rather more acute, the presence of differences
and variety rather more salient, the contrasts and judgments rather more
commonly felt.
Moreover,
any explanation must involve a consideration of the social and political and
economic environment, historical precedents, and then consideration of
individual responsibility for their situation. In general if your situation is
auspicious, you are much less in need of your individual resources, than if you
are in an inauspicious situation.
So if you want
to explain heterogeneity and hierarchy, and why some individual is lower on
that totem pole or why someone is on top, you must start out with understanding
that environment and how it is auspicious or inauspicious. I do not believe
this is so much a political position, as a scholarly one—but perhaps I am wrong
here.
Two other considerations: Cities are in general sites of
alienation, although neighborhoods may well be solidaritous. Hence, when things
go awry, it may be hard to get support from others, although there are more
others—so there is a balance between numbers and alienation. And, second,
anything that depends on interactions (infectious disease, pollution,
buying/selling, crime, …) is likely proportional to the square of the number of
people in an area—N2 although that N might be the number of people
you are in contact with or potentially in contact with through communications
or transportation (over some period of time).
Neighborhoods
(as in Sampson, Great American City)
Neighborhoods differ, “everyone” knows about each of them, have
different levels of wealth, as well as levels of disorder, not to speak of
class and race. Cities are a montage of neighborhoods and there is a flow of
people among neighborhoods, often similar ones.
Sorting by neighborhood is either: Neighborhoods
choose people or people choose neighborhoods. In any case, people enact their
neighborhood expectations, and that is enforced (what Sampson calls “collective
efficacy”).
Disorder is differently perceived (vs. objectively
measured). Crime and disorder have a root cause it would seem, but Disorder may
not be indicative of Crime argues Sampson.
There is spatial inequality derived in part of from
concentrated and cumulative (dis-)advantages. Also there are other worlds, so
to speak, cutting across neighborhoods, as in the informal economy, and when people
have jobs that are not reliable.
There is lots of room for individual responsibility
and initiative or going-along. But always, in the neighborhood context.
People escape their neighborhoods, but this is not
easy—going up or down. Most people and most neighborhoods are stable, for
better or worse.
To make Neighborhoods better: make them less violent,
give kids better schooling and early childhood education, immigrants move in and
occupy a neighborhood. There are lots of efforts to make neighborhoods better
through urban planning, development, etc. It is not clear when and if they work
well. There is as well the tragedies of
urban renewal although those who are displaced may then find a better life.
The Economy of Cities
You surely do not need a city
to have an economy, but cities create the opportunity for a lively
economy: lots of buyers and sellers and
manufacturers and importers, and lots of connections to other cities and to the
hinterlands and to foreign economies.
Diversity
and Division of Labor leads to lots of exchanges and often to transformations
of the society. New modes of
organization and communication and manufacture—technology—allow for
transformation.
Location
matters. Centers are valuable. People choose to live, work, do business based
on quite local factors—if they have choices.
Migration is
much like technology, introducing new disruptive forces.
Corruption
and informal enterprises lead to an underground economy, one that in effect
provides the above- ground economy with some of what it needs.
Stability
and order are crucial, since so many people are in such close proximity.
Taxes and
property rights, often national rather than urban, make for amenity and
security and so for investment and risk-taking
Cities with
great inequality (of whatever sort), and distinguish this from diversity, are
less stable.
Amenities
such as parks and the arts and … have to be provided, and often are best
provided through the state.
Cities do
decline and rise, usually over longer periods, neighborhoods too. Competition,
war, invention.
Propinquity
still seems to matter. Face-to-face is important in many areas. So the big
question we still ask, 150+ years after the railroads, is how will such
communication and transportation technologies alter urban life.
And neighborhood economies are often important, but with
better transport (and freight) those economies tend to become larger in spatial
extent.
How Cities are Built
Cities are built
by government, by private individuals, by builders and real estate developers.
The land may be owned by government, and leased for say 99 years, or it may be
sold by government to raise revenue, or given away by government to encourage
settlement. There are regulations concerning safety and health, zoning, size and
type of building, etc. Regulations are in general not liked by owners until
their neighbors do something that hurts their property. Land and improvements
are often taxed to pay for government services, in part because it is hard to
hide such assets. Infrastructure is in part provided by government, in part by
"natural monopolists" which are private entities (and so they receive
exclusive licenses from government). Some uses are relatively protected from
taxation.
Strong
property rights encourage development and building. Weak rights make it hard to
justify improvements with longer term payoffs.
Planning
in terms of comprehensive plans, zoning, incentives, etc. may be merely
coercive, from a authoritarian government. In more liberal societies, planning
is indicative or guiding, giving greater certainty to developers and residents
about what will be nearby. Presumably, there could be a market for rights to
build, or compensation to neighbors for stuff they might not prefer and to
encourage them not to go to the courts. But regulation has proved helpful,
since litigation is costly, has uncertain outcomes, and takes a long time to
get settled.
As
for property, it might be real or immovable property of land and buildings, but
it may include air rights, permission for floor-area ratios, or mineral rights
under the land. Property may be under long-term leases. There are rules about
when government can take over property for public purposes, compensating the
owners. And there are markets for air rights, etc., where someone who has such
rights but does not use them might sell them to someone who can then use them.
Places
are valuable because they are well connected to other places, so roads,
transit, ports, industry, will affect the value of property and the possibility
of certain kinds of economic activity.
In
the US, the federal government plays a very large role in city development,
from guaranteeing home loans, building some roads, setting standards for safety
and health. Tax rules can encourage or discourage speculative building or
office towers.
There
is always an intimate relationship of public and private in urban development.
So, if you want fire and police protection, in most places you have to pay
taxes, often based on property values. But one might have private police and
fire provision, but this is quite rare.
And
of course, government builds public schools and parks, although there is
private provision of such as well.
Different eras have different stories of city
building. I have focused mostly on the contemporary US, here.
Where the money comes from to enable city development.
Banks make short term construction loans, with a sense that
when the building is done they will be able to get their money back. For the
longer run, there are mortgages, since almost no one has the money to just
purchase a building or unit outright. Moreover, in general, if you want to
sell, there need to be buyers, so it helps if the economy is in good shape, the
loan institutions are working well, and buyers have enough credit-worthiness to
pay. Hence homeowners have an interest
in the well-being of immigrants, at least in LA, since they are likely to be
buyers in the future and unless they have good incomes they won’t be in the
market and so your home will fetch less than you hoped.
a. To encourage home lending, the
Federal government has developed loan guarantee programs (FHA, VET HOME LOANS…)
and institutions that make home loans—Fannie Mae…
b. To encourage investors to get into
lending for mortgages, securities backed by a bunch of mortgages (and their
repayment) have been invented, with all sorts of wonderful “improvements” to
make them more attractive in terms of risk and reward. Unfortunately, many of
the mortgages were much riskier than advertised, and so these securities
tumbled in value when the economy hit a blip—people walked away from their
mortgages. What happens is that if a random number of mortgagees happen to
default, most others continue to make their payments, and the risks are
moderate. But if a large number walk away at the same time, the risk becomes
much larger, the rewards correspondingly smaller.
c. Since
building takes time, it is possible that if a bunch of builders/developers
decide to start a project at the same time, and the timing is not optimal,
there will be an oversupply and so lots of problems.
Globalization
The main point is
that cities are gathering places for diverse people, they have to work together
since not only are the close-by each other, they need each other. And they need
as well the people at other cities.
As for globalization, per se. Basically, either
because of division of labor and specialization, resources, dominance (as in
colonialism), or capital value, there is an enormous trade in goods and skills
among cities, often far apart. Migrations, planned and unplanned, create many
groups within major cities, each group having different origins, looks,
customs, yet they all eventually in a generation or two homogenize but not
completely. There is still hierarchies and domination, but somewhat different
than conventional colonialism. Race or nationality are modulated by class and
income and religion, so diversity is the new normal. In the course of things,
there is discrimination and unfair treatment, just what eventually creates
problems that make cities tumultuous.
The City in Gravity
Geographers and urban planners
explain how parts of the city influence other parts using a formula much like
Newton’s law of gravitation. Einstein’s extension of Newton again shows how the
paths of falling objects determine the distribution of mass-energy, and vice versa.
Correspondingly, in a city being nearby matters, and where and when you go
depends on what there is to do there. We really have no such precise theory for
cities as we do for the universe. Still, we might think of cities as modeled by
the cosmos.
The Big Bang’s expanding universe rapidly cools down, in
stages not unlike steam becoming water becoming ice. And eventually, it is cool
enough and there is time enough to form stars and galaxies as bits of dust
gravitate toward each other. So cities form and expand, and as they expand
people and developers form neighborhoods–as people and activities gravitate, so
to speak, toward each other. And, just as stars might eventually die or
explode, perhaps to eventually form new stars, so neighborhoods may dissipate
as they become too dense and chaotic for their residents, leading to new
neighborhoods.
In a patterned history, the stars’ individual ages are
indicated by their color and brightness. So in neighborhoods, time is marked by
patterned histories of development and decay (and rebirth). And, like Black
Holes, cities attract everything in their region. As for Black Holes, much of
the detailed particulars of each person so attracted are erased by city life
and its anonymity.
These
city-cosmos analogies participate in a long tradition of notional
correspondences of the microcosm and the macrocosm.
Sounds of the City
The sights, sounds, and smells of a neighborhood are distinctive and
pervasive. We might know where we are by the odors or the noise of a place:
tanning factories or botanical gardens, freeways adjacent to or distant from
residential neighborhoods. So we might document the urban sensorium, in
particular the aural background or ambient sound of different parts of Los
Angeles.
F. Murray Shafer has argued that the sound of modern cities is lo-fi,
with lots of noise hiding significant sounds at a distance.
We have literary evidence of the aural environment:
the sounds of the bells in a city in a novel, the clatter in a textile factory.
Nowadays, we might develop accurate archives of the urban aural environment
recording in digital surround-sound, records that can be preserved
indefinitely.
In one Hispanic neighborhood in Los Angeles, I was
recording the sounds of children playing in a school yard. The neighborhood was
reasonably quiet, although freeways surround the neighborhood and add an
unavoidable background hum. Then I
heard, faintly in the distance, the call of a lady selling tamales, riding on
on her tricycle, closer and louder: “Tamales! … TAMALES!...”
When I was a child in Brooklyn, there would be vendors
coming around offering to sharpen knives or selling fruit and vegetables. Here
in this Hispanic neighborhood, it makes sense to offer tamales, and by moving
around much as do those vendors, she enlarges her customer base.
To appreciate what is going on in this neighborhood,
you have to pay attention and listen to those everyday sounds.
Real Cities
People readily assert just what is wrong with Los Angeles, or big
cities, or urban life. Yes, cities are unavoidably congested, conflict ridden,
hierarchized, and alienating. They are as well the sources of invention and
entrepreneurship, political empowerment, social mobility, and community.
Cities almost always have too many people and activities.
They are congested. They are crowded and noisy and messy. That also means they
allow for lots of interaction among peoples and institutions, just the source
of their vitality.
Cities are conflict ridden just because they are a confluence of
cultures and interests and peoples.
Adam Smith’s division of labor and specialization is
further articulated, just because there is high spatial density of people in a
city and the availability of goods from other places such as the hinterlands or
other cities. (It is unlikely you grow your own food.) That, too, makes for
productivity and opportunity.
In cities, hierarchies rather than being based on
hereditary status and land, are likely based specialized talents and skills, on
race and ethnicity, and on wealth—and they are often expressed spatially
through where people live and work. Urban hierarchies do allow for mobility for
some, while being all too present for most.
And cities are alienating,
for whatever solidarity or community one might have had is now erased. But,
given the varieties of peoples, new communities develop, and there is freedom
to forget your past and start anew.
For cities, what we
most complain about is the source of what we value the most. We are stuck with
a cornucopia of opportunity and the burdens of constraint.
Appendix: What We Might Know About
Cities
We know about cities through the means we have of observing them. Here
I want to focus on our visual and other sensory knowledge of the city. I will
draw from observational astronomy and the nature of stars to suggest something
about the nature of cities.
Observational astronomers know about the universe
through the information we on earth receive that is electromagnetic: light,
visible and ultraviolet and infrared, x-rays, and radio waves. (Cosmic rays
consisting of elementary particles and high-energy photons play an important
but lesser role. Gravitational waves have yet to be directly observed.)
Astronomer have to develop better detectors of those electromagnetic signals
(telescopes for the most part) and find more transparent places to put them—say
Mauna Kea in Hawaii or on a satellite such as the Hubble.
For cities, one can do much better. One can talk to
people and watch what they do, map various phenomena, analyze economic and
other such data. Remote sensing as done by the astronomers is also available,
although the remote is much closer to the phenomena (drones, airplanes,
satellites). Other than talking to people, these methods all demand a complex
organized society to produce the data and sensors as part of its bureaucratic
processes.
For the moment, I want to focus on what we might
observe visually. If we are on the ground, doing interviews and fieldwork with
a camera in hand, we can ask probing questions when unexpected information
comes our way, record movies of interesting phenomena in space and time, and
look behind us or nearby to see more of what is going on. We can get closer or
get another perspective and angle or check in-back-of by moving ourselves; we
can get a more detailed image with a telephoto lens. We can get more in our
frame using a wide-angle lens.
What is outside the frame, whatever its dimensions and
proportions, is not available to us.
(Sound recording devices can be set to in effect start recording several
seconds before we press the record button, and the “frame” provided by a
microphone is often all round.) We might record many images, each with a
different spatial perspective, or also at different times, or of similar
phenomena at different locations or times—in effect a tomography.
Our cameras will provide us with lots of detail,
especially if they are provided with good lenses, we employ a tripod or hold
the camera steady, and our sensors are sufficiently resolving of detail.
Digital sensors are remarkably good since their capacity to provide high
definition only starts disappearing, and rapidly so, when the detail on the
sensor is a bit less than two pixels wide, while film’s resolution falls off
much more slowly even for details that are as large as several grain sizes on
the film. Charles Marville’s photographs of Paris streets in about 1870 provide
extraordinary detail. He used a negative the size of letter paper, a lens with
a comparatively small opening so he had lots of depth of field, and the
wet-plate emulsion is grainless. He surely has less resolution than modern
cameras and sensors, but his negative is more than 60 times larger than is a
35mm negative (and perhaps 1000 times larger than your cellphone camera’s
sensor—not really a fair comparison to be sure).
Eventually, an image will fall apart under sufficient
enlargement, in part because of aberrations of the lens, poor focusing or lack
of depth of field, or camera motion that blurs the image.
Of course, unlike our eyes, cameras do not move to
follow and explore events, unless the photographer chooses to do so. On the
other hand, photographs provide remarkable detail in space and time, especially
if we have suites of photographs spread out over an area and repeatedly made
over a period of time, as in the satellite surveillance photographs in the
CORONA program of the 1960s.
Our camera might be an automatic camera, with perhaps
no adjustments to be made by ourselves, since it has sensors and algorithms
that make for good images, given the lighting, the nature of the subject (e.g.
faces), and the particular peculiarities of the sensor (film, digital) and lens
(distortions corrected digitally).
Or we might have what is in effect a fancy box camera,
fancy being my term of art for a camera where we focus, choose the lens opening
and shutter speed, and the film and its speed, and perhaps as well chose the
lens. Such was the view camera of old. The fancy box camera in the hands of an
experienced and thoughtful picture maker is likely to make more informative
images than is the automatic camera. But for most of us the automatic camera is
a better choice. And such automatic cameras tend to be small (as in
smartphones), and the best camera to use is the one you have with you.
Cosmologically, much of what we see is a consequences
of gravity, and then of nuclear and particle forces. Gravity in its 1/r2 form pushes cosmic
material to agglomerate and then become more and more dense; eventually if
there is enough of mass involved in such an agglomeration we’ll have a star,
one that is powered by nuclear interactions at its core when the gravitational
pressure is so large that nuclei and particles can no longer ignore each other.
So we might say that cities agglomerate, perhaps
because there is a deliberate or random concentration of people who then
attract others who want to interact with them. What is crucial is to realize
that for stars of a certain mass their history is determined by their nuclear
physics (the Hertzsprung-Russell diagram); and eventually, if they are quite
massive, their history is determined by very strong gravitational forces
leading to white dwarfs, brown dwarfs, supernovae, neutron stars, and black
holes: that is, either leading to dead stars that stop sending out signals of
their existence (they’ve run out of energy to burn), or stars that are so
gravitationally dense that in their turbulent lives, they emit gravity energy
(gravitational waves); or stars that explode sending out lots of material that
can then eventually agglomerate again, or stars that have such powerful
gravitational forces they absorb anything that comes close to them and what we
see are the death throes of those absorbed stars.
Schematically, cities are much the same. We may
discern paths and prospective histories for some cities, but nothing so
determined as for stars since there are many influences along the way that are
external to a city (other cities, federal governments,…). In general, as for
the Big Bang, the evolution of a city is best seen in logarithmic time: that is
the first months, then the first years, the first decades, the first centuries. Put differently, if we think of time as
delimited by events, significant events appear at time scales that start out
small, and subsequent events eventually appear at times scales that are many
times larger. Namely, rather than using a clock and ruler to understand cities,
use your historian’s hat and select significant events as the appropriate
time-scales. Now, cities may act much
like black holes in that they absorb populations from the hinterlands and in
effect destroy the individual histories as those populations as they become
members of the city and alienated from their very particular pasts.
Moreover, at any time in the evolution or history of a
city, there is a connection between the people, institutions, and the built
environment (we’ll call these three “people”) and the spatial patterns and
movements in a city. In effect the people create a geography, while,
reciprocally, the geography and shape of space and time guide those populations
in their movements and history.
In general relativity, John A. Wheeler said,
Mass tells
Spacetime how to Curve, and Spacetime (Curvature) tells Mass how to Move (Fall
Down, that is, gravity).
In our context, we might say:
People tell
Cities how and where and when to create circulation, and Circulation tells
people how to go about their business.
The geometry of spacetime is the same as the distribution of matter and
energy in the universe, whereby geometry I mean the straight lines defined by
the path of light (electromagnetism again). Here, the networks of movements and
the networks of people are the same: they define each other.
These
analogies are far-fetched. Still, I think they allow us to think about cities
in useful ways. So, for example, planning creates possibilities for future
circulation (understood broadly), in effect it gives us an option to be called
upon in the future if we need it. So we are not quite a general relativistic
system, for we can insert new masses into the city in a deliberate way.
Photographing in New York City
The
street becomes your museum; . . . you want [your work] to commence from life,
and that's in the street now. Walker Evans, 1971
A
city street will tell you as much in its way as your morning newspaper….One
fact it will not only tell you but rub it into you hard: everybody works.” April
1946 WE re a Fortune article.
I'm
not a photographer. I'm a columnist who writes with pictures. Bill Cunningham
(all NYTimes, 3Jy16):
You
need the street . . . [to complement the
designer fashion shows, so as to see how people adapt the fashion to their own
lives, and the evening hours]
I'm looking for
the stunners.
Just
remember they need you. You don't need them. (BC re your dates)
He let the streets talk to him. . . . He goes out for several days
and sees the story emerge. (Simone Oliver re BC
A city is a viscous dense congested interacting fluid of particles
(people, institutions, the built environment), particles that interact through
collision and exchange. Cities foster networks and lines of flow. In that
network fluid, there are density concentrations and so clustering of particles,
and confinement, so that some particles are not to be freed from each other
(never to be seen individuated, always bound to the flow). Dynamically, what
people do and the city’s physical and institutional structure mirror each other
(albeit with mismatches that adjust in time and space), as in general
relativity ala Wheeler[1], and there are supportive
flows of pecuniary resources, materials, and communications, as well as flows
of entrepreneurship and consumption. There is an impetus to differentiation and
diversity, one that leads to both heterogeneity and hierarchy. [What is the
impetus, and why heterogeneity and hierarchy??] There is a division of labor;
there are markets to distribute alienated goods and services. Yet there are
neighborhoods, in which there is greater uniformity and restricted diversity—in
part because people enact their neighborhood’s values and pressures, learning
how to be seen and how to behave so that they belong. Neighborhoods are in this
sense self-conscious. On the streets, it is manifest that you are in a place
and a time. [Ideas to be inserted:; cosmological models such as black holes,
big bang, stellar evolution…]
My photographs of New York City display its being a
jumble of accumulated accretions, yet at the right perspective and distance the
city appears orderly and repetitious. When you get much closer, that orderliness becomes a voyeur’s dream of
fascinating detail and peculiarity.
Outside of busy Manhattan, what you see is lots of brick and some sort
of plastic siding, in apartment and commercial buildings and in single-family
and two-family row housing—with signs of distinctiveness in the names on the
buildings, displays of religious symbols, and in the choice of siding. At the ends
of the subways lines, in Brooklyn, Queens, and the Bronx, there are basic
stores, perhaps a McDonald’s and some
chain stores, and brick and siding—what is called “transit oriented
development,” but now after fifty to one-hundred-plus years of ups and downs, a
palimpsest. Some of the time, those end-stations are in fact surrounded by
vigorous local shopping, massive flows of people from busses to the Subway, and stores radiating
out in all directions, sometimes only along a main street or under the elevated
line. There is exposed infrastructure that reaches down to surround the built
environment, supports and girders marking streets or actually coming in contact
with the sides of homes. The Subways provide some of the most vivid
infrastructure, as well as aerial and subterranean viewpoints. The voyeur can
look into the plate glass windows of restaurants and bars find “the right
people” lounging in their consumption; the open doorways of general stores, the
less-right people finding their latest fix; the entryways of boutiques and
chain-stores with twenties and thirties (yet to be in tow of children) or local
working people shopping. There is as well industrial production, open garages
and cellars, backrooms, and the brightly lit tunnels to underground garages--all
right in front of you. There may be stalls of fruit and vegetables, and often
people providing self-conscious displays of autonomy and iconoclasm. Just to
the side of carefully tended facades, there are interstices and
alleys--sometimes they are parking lots or just parking for residents,
sometimes pathways to the rear entrances of buildings, sometimes service
entrances decorated with dumpsters and strewn garbage.
Of course, many
block-faces are repetitions of tract housing and apartment buildings, with a
sprinkle of schools and churches.
Often, neighborhoods
are of no distinction, although their residents believe their particular
neighborhood is of longstanding distinguished characteristics and qualities,
only appreciated by residents and the cognoscenti. Neighborhood residents work
hard to keep up (or down) their neighborhood, enacting what is expected and
suggesting to neighbors that they had better keep in line. Throughout the city,
fancy parts or much less fancy, life is ordinary—in part because people learn
how to act according to their place, modulating their enactment to suit places
as they move through the city. Surely, photographers will provide images of the
weird and idiosyncratic, but we see those images as such because most of life is
ordinary and we have learned to ignore, actively and deliberately, anything
that will disturb us.
Most block-faces and
their streets are peopled by children, parents, and the elderly, with little
action except when children are going to school or adults going to work. There
is very little of the proverbial stoop life, or the elderly women looking out
the windows patrolling the street (ala Jane Jacobs). Commercial street life and life in the Subway
is meant to be flow-friendly and unobtrusive. Vendors provide immediate needs
whether for falafel or umbrellas or notions. There are waves of people (coming
from emptying trains at this station, say), moving quite deliberately and
quickly, and the meeting or apparent clash of those waves, when people are
going to the right exits or subway platforms or place in town, is an apparently
careless but unobtrusive interaction of waves (what physicists would call
“quasi-elastic scattering,” soliton-like), waves of people threading through
each other, individuals in that wave feeling its general direction but
adjusting their pathways (toward their own immediate destination) while
avoiding oncoming distractions and
collisions—as if they could sense and so
predict what will happen in the next two seconds (which in fact they can do).
[I am not sure what molecules are actually doing in a fluidic-flow, but it must
somehow be like this, a guided random walk?--albeit they do not experience
longer-range forces since they do not have eyes and ears. Put differently, I
believe differential equations do work in this realm, albeit with viscosity.
And what the molecules do feel are collisions with nearby molecules, so that if
they are not in the flow, they will feel forces that push them back in.]
Unlike the renderings
of various proposed urban plans and developments, most people, in most
neighborhoods, on most Subway trains, on most streets, are not smartly dressed,
although many may try to be fashionable or otherwise display their taste and
preferences. (There are streets where people do so dress up, but rarely are
they in the neighborhoods.)
Urban
Tomography
For cities before 1850, we only know
about the urban sensorium, our experiences of sight, sound, smell, feel, from
vivid descriptions and graphics. Nowadays, we can do better.
In
the 1850s and 1860s Charles
Marville photographed more
than 500 streets of Paris, both before they were eviscerated and after they
were rebuilt under Napoleon III’s orders with the direction of Baron
Haussmann—creating the Paris we know today with its grand boulevards.
I
learned from Marville that it is vital to make suites of images, much as are
made in a CAT scan of your brain. Such tomography, the prefix tomo is the Latin
for a slice, as in a horizontal slice of the brain, allows one to see in
multiple dimensions.
In
our case, the dimensions are time and variations within a subject matter. You
want to achieve a general sense that would include those manifold slice.
In
Los Angeles, I have photographed the facades of 800+ storefront houses of
worship, people at work at 225 industrial sites including at the Ports of Los
Angeles and Long Beach and at the iconic County-USC hospital, and all the
electrical power stations of the Department of Water and Power. And we have
recorded the sounds of Los Angeles in high-quality calibrated surround sound.
We
have also rephotographed the sites Marville photographed in Paris but now 135
years later, to compare then and now.
Google
Street View and social media are wonderful but also quite partial. You have to
go out and be there and look and make your own photographs.
Our
work is meant to create a living present for the future. Systematic, indexed,
and archived documentation captures a legacy that will remain for future
generations to study and enjoy.
Detroit as the City of Industry
In the early 1930s, Edsel Ford
commissioned Diego Rivera (1886-1957), the Mexican muralist, to paint, by means
of fresco, an enclosed courtyard of the Detroit Institute of Arts Museum. The
work is a paean to Nature, Industry, Civilization, and People. Ford’s interest
in industry and overlapped with Rivera’s Marxist interest in modernism.
There is an education in studying all four walls of the courtyard.
Henry
Ford, Edsel’s father, had developed the River Rouge manufacturing plant
downriver from Detroit, integrated so that it took in raw materials and put out
Ford automobiles. It was a City of Industry. Rivera’s panoply of images show
the process of manufacture, from the making of steel to the sewing of the
automobile’s upholstery. Featured in portraits were the actual actors:
the industrial capitalist Henry Ford, the cultivated and elite Edsel, the
managers and engineers, and the supervisors and workers at the furnaces and
sewing machines. There is a mutual dependence of the managers and engineers
with the workers, while the capitalists are literally sidelined.
Rivera
displayed modern industry: aviation, water supply, energy production, and
chemicals and pharmaceuticals. As well as Nature, from its geological strata
that made for resource-rich places, in cities and hinterlands, places that made
this City of Industry possible, to generativity in childbirth. Those
children and their parents, who worked at River Rouge, were portrayed as of
many races (as the notion was then understood) with complex and rich cultures.
Here
is a city (even in the Great Depression), at the nexus of transport and
resources, a universe of capital, people, and goods, as well as of labor
conflict and eventually war producti
[1] Mass tells Spacetime how to
Curve, and Spacetime (Curvature) tells Mass how to Move (Fall Down, that is,
gravity). OR People tell Cities how and
where and when to create circulation, and Circulation tells people how to go
about their business.
Comments
Post a Comment